Sadly,
economic policy is guided by neither facts nor ideas — it is guided by
power. Ending austerity will require more than Excel spreadsheets alone.
It
has not been a good couple of weeks for the conservative class warriors
of the global austerity project. First, new data revealed that
austerity measures in Portugal — long a neoliberal poster child for
EU/IMF-imposed reforms — are failing to deliver; then the IMF got into a fight
with the British government, complaining that UK austerity measures are
hurting the economy; later a former IMF official warned that Europe’s austerity measures are untenable, while the head of the world’s biggest hedge fund attacked the EU and UK for their austerity drive, arguing that “you have to spend money”.
On the same day, the head of the European Commission declared that austerity had reached a political limit in Europe; a day later the Spanish government announced that it will ease its austerity push; a day after that, Italy’s freshly-designated center-left Prime Minister immediately called for an easing of austerity; right as new data showed that austerity-induced unemployment has now surpassed
Great Depression-era levels in Southern Europe. And all the while,
German Chancellor Angela Merkel — the undisputed standard-bearer of the
European austerity movement — finds herself under increasing political pressure to just relax and stop hurting everyone else around her.
No surprise, then, that the Financial Times is now forced to conclude that “the Eurozone anti-austerity camp is on the rise”, while its lead economics commentator Martin Wolf laments that
“tens of millions are now suffering unnecessarily” as a result of
failed austerity measures. It’s what the Left has been saying for
years – not just since the start of the European debt crisis three years
ago, but ever since the Great Depression; through the “lost decade” of
the 1980s debt crisis in Latin America, the IMF-imposed tragedies in
East-Asia in the late 1990s, the austerity-induced financial meltdown
and record default in Argentina in late 2001, and virtually every single
crisis that occurred in between.
But
it was in the midst of all of this that a major bombshell hit the
academic debate on austerity: the Great Reinhart-Rogoff Excel
Spreadsheet Debacle. In case you didn’t hear about this yet: just a
week-and-a-half ago, a 28-year-old graduate student at the University of
Maryland published a paper
with two of his supervisors that basically destroyed the last-remaining
academic “credibility” of the global austerity movement. In their myth-busting publication, Herndon, Ash and Pollin (HAP) show that a widely cited
2010 paper by Harvard economists Reinhart and Rogoff — which claimed
that a debt load above 90% of GDP significantly slows down growth — was
in fact based on faulty data, skewered weighting and a sloppy Excel
spreadsheet error. Fixing these “mistakes”, HAP showed how the seemingly
strong correlation between high indebtedness and slow growth virtually
evaporates.
Why is this relevant, you may wonder? Well, as Nobel Prize-winning economist Paul Krugman has rightly pointed out, the Reinhart-Rogoff paper “was
surely the most influential economic analysis of recent years.” It was
cited by key law- and policymakers on both sides of the Atlantic,
including US House Budget Committee Chairman and former
Vice-Presidential candidate Paul Ryan; EU Economic and Monetary Affairs
Commissioner Olli Rehn; and the President of the Bundesbank, Jens
Weidmann, who is known as one of Germany’s leading austerity hawks. The
Reinhart-Rogoff paper was, in short, the number one piece of “factual
evidence” for the already shaky neoliberal proposition that “a high debt
load is necessarily bad” and “austerity necessarily good”.
Of course we already knew that this was nonsense. The idea of an “expansionary fiscal contraction”
is an academic fairy tale at best and an Orwellian justification for an
unabashed market fundamentalist class project at worst. When an economy
is in free fall and private investors rush for the exit, the worst
thing a government could possibly do is to slam on the brakes and
retract the only remaining source of investment in the economy. Ever
since Keynes’ contributions after the Great Depression, this is as much
as a self-evidence. But the real question we should be asking is not
whether austerity makes sense for the official purposes declared by its
adherents, but whether it makes sense for the adherents themselves. In
other words, we shouldn’t be asking whether austerity contributes to
growth (we’ve known for decades that it doesn’t); what we should really
be asking is whether austerity contributes to the interests of those who
promote it.
When we ask this question, a different world suddenly emerges. Now austerity is no longer just a “dangerous idea”
destroying the lives of millions; and it no longer follows that
austerity can simply be replaced with a more “sensible” idea (like
monetary and fiscal stimulus) through the rigorous provision of factual
evidence by leading experts possessing PhDs and other fancy titles.
Rather, austerity becomes a profoundly ideological class project.
It is one thing to note that “austerity has failed” in its stated
objective of raising growth and solving the debt problem; it is quite
another to observe that it has actually succeeded quite spectacularly in
its real objective of serving the narrow interests of the top 1% at the
expense of almost everyone else. In this respect, it is safe to say
that austerity was never supposed to raise growth in the first place: it
was meant to discipline labor all along, making the average population
pay for a devastating financial crisis that was caused by the rampant
speculation of a tiny financial oligarchy.
Let
me take a step back here and describe — at the risk of great
over-simplification — three different theories that dominate the debate
in political economy. The first theory, held by many orthodox economists
and rational choice theorists in political science, would argue that
facts and evidence play a crucial role in shaping policy. Simply put,
rational and self-interested government actors always represent some
clearly-defined national interest, and changing analyses of the facts
can help them to re-assess this national interest and redirect policy
accordingly. This is the so-called “technocratic” position taken by
Reinhart and Rogoff in a pathetic attempt to defend themselves in the New York Times, complaining
that “our critics have politicized the issue”, as if their own position
in the austerity debate is somehow a completely objective and
“non-political” assessment of the true national interest of heavily
indebted countries.
A second theory,
adhered to mostly by Keynesian economists and constructivist scholars in
sociology and political science, argues that not facts but ideas –
defined as socially constructed understandings of what social reality
is and should be like — guide policy. Most Keynesians and
constructivists accept the “fact” that different policymakers may hold
different ideas on how to solve a particular problem. These scholars,
inspired by Max Weber’s thesis that ideas are the “switchmen” of
history, therefore focus on the role of ideas in constituting social
reality and bringing about important changes in economic policy. This
constructivist view, recently expressed in an important new book on austerity by Mark Blyth, reflects Keynes’ dictum that:
The ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed the world is ruled by little else. Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any intellectual influence, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist. Madmen in authority, who hear voices in the air, are distilling their frenzy from some academic scribbler of a few years back. I am sure that the power of vested interests is vastly exaggerated compared with the gradual encroachment of ideas.
The
third theory, arising out of Marx’s critique of political economy and
critical theory more generally, argues that ideas are nice and dandy,
but ultimately rather inconsequential if you do not have the power to
implement them. For these scholars, ideas can have quite an important
influence on political outcomes when “the field is open”, so to speak;
but in times of either hegemonic consolidation or outright political
repression, even manifestly false ideas can reign supreme as long as
they are backed up by the right combination of political institutions,
socio-economic structures, ideological preconceptions, and — ultimately —
military might. These different forms of power help to strengthen
prevailing orthodoxies while disciplining any potential dissent. In this
view, then, facts and ideas are ultimately secondary to the broader
pattern of class struggle in which they are wielded as weapons.
Which
of these three theories is the most credible — and which of them best
describes the politics of austerity? The answer should be self-evident
by now. Thirty years of austerity measures, from Mexico in 1982 to
Greece in 2013, should be more than enough evidence that dangerously
misguided ideas — as long as they are backed up with sufficient
political and economic power — can long survive their thorough
discrediting in the face of obvious facts. After a “lost decade” of
IMF-imposed austerity, the Mexican economy in 1989 was still 11% smaller
than it was at the start of the Latin American debt crisis in 1982;
after the IMF paid a visit to East-Asia during its financial crisis of
1997-’98, it took Thailand and Indonesia seven and eight years,
respectively, to regain their average income levels of 1996; and today,
three years after the EU and IMF first “bailed out” Greece and imposed
their tragic austerity measures, the Greek economy is a shocking 20
percent smaller than it was at the start of the crisis.
We knew all
these things. Yet our politicians continued to impose the same
disastrous austerity measures — over, and over, and over again. In a
public debate at the European University Institute last year, I scolded German Finance Minister Wolfgang Schäuble for knowing all of this: he knows Greece is collapsing; he knows austerity is making it worse; he knows that even the IMF now formally admits this; he knows the bottomless pit is not Greece but the banks; he knows there is no way Greece will ever recover under the German austerity diktat;
yet Schäuble and the global elite continue to impose the same austerity
measures — over, and over, and over again. If facts or ideas truly
mattered in policymaking, you would think we would have come up with
some better ideas by now. But the sad truth, as always, is that the
facts matter only if you have the power to impose your version of them
onto the others.
Does this mean the
Reinhart-Rogoff debacle and the ongoing discrediting of the austerity
agenda is entirely meaningless? No, it doesn’t. Facts and ideas matter —
but only insofar as they can be wielded as weapons in an ongoing class
struggle. Now that the “facts” uncovered by Reinhart and Rogoff and the
“dangerous ideas” promoted by the global austerity movement have been so
thoroughly discredited, let us wield our weapons wisely — by
recognizing the “fact” that we cannot rely on facts and ideas alone to
change the world. As the Greek anti-austerity protesters who faced a
bloody police crackdown on Syntagma Square in June 2011 know only all
too well, after ideologically disarming the neoliberal hegemony that
underpins today’s austerity drive, we will still have to confront the
material power that backs it up. And that, unfortunately, will require a
lot more than Excel spreadsheets alone.
No comments:
Post a Comment