Buckling
under the structural power of its private creditors, the European
periphery seems destined for a lost decade of austerity. What can be
done?
Now that the botched bailout
of Cyprus has reignited the flames of Europe’s never-ending debt
debacle, it suddenly appears to be all the rage again to make historical
comparisons between the ongoing euro crisis and previous crises in
Latin America. Piling on to a long list of comparisons between Greece
and Argentina, for instance, Paul Krugman last week invoked Argentina’s 2001 corralito
as a precedent for the imposition of withdrawal limits in Cyprus,
claiming this to be the first part in a script that will eventually lead
to Cyprus’ euro exit.
Yet the longer
the European debt crisis drags on, the more obvious it becomes that the
appropriate comparison here is not with the explosive collapse of
Argentina in 2001-’02 — in which total financial meltdown led to a
spontaneous popular uprising that witnessed over 20 protesters killed in
two nights, five presidents unseated in two weeks, and the largest-ever
sovereign debt default imposed on private creditors in the history of
capitalism — but rather with a much more destructive and drawn-out
event: the Latin American debt crisis of the 1980s.
Latin America’s Lost Decade
What
set the Latin American debt crisis of 1982 apart from the Argentine
crisis of 2001-’02 — and why is this difference relevant for Europe
today? Well, first of all, Argentina actually refused to honor a large
part of its external debts. In December 2001, it defaulted on $93
billion of public external debt and subsequently restructured its
outstanding obligations in a highly forceful setting, offering its
private creditors a take-it-or-leave-it deal that eventually saw a
majority of 93% of creditors accepting a repayment of a mere 35 cents on
the dollar.
The crisis of the 1980s,
by contrast, did not witness any form of debt repudiation. Although
dozens of Latin American countries became embroiled in the crisis, only
three countries — Brazil, Argentina and Peru — briefly experimented with
temporary debt moratoriums or reduced debt repayments; but all of them
eventually fell back into line and dutifully kept repaying their debts.
Interestingly, this remarkable degree of debtor discipline contrasts
sharply with the wave of defaults that rocked the world during the
crisis of the 1930s.
The subsequent
economic trajectories of Argentina post-2001 and Latin America in the
1980s therefore could not be more dramatically opposed. While the
Argentine economy boomed back to life in spectacular fashion in the wake
of its 2001 default, Latin America in the 1980s gradually sank deeper
and deeper into the abyss. After years and years of neoliberal austerity
and reform, by 1990 real income in Mexico was still lower than it had
been in 1982. Not surprisingly, therefore, the 1980s became known in
Latin America as the década perdida: the lost decade.
Why Not Default?
This
brings us to another question: if default was still considered a
legitimate policy response in the 1930s, and proved to be such a fiscal
catharsis in Argentina in 2001, then why did Latin America not default en masse in the 1980s — and why does Southern Europe not default en masse
today? The answer to this question, my own PhD research on Latin
America suggests, lies in the dramatically changed nature of the global
financial system — and the implications these structural changes have
had on the power of private creditors.
In
the 1930s, sovereign lending was largely organized on the basis of bond
finance: big banks would bring together large and dispersed groups of
small-scale investors, who would then put up the capital required to buy
up large amounts of government bonds. The purchase of these bonds
provided Latin American governments with the credit they needed and
provided the banks in New York and the City of London with handsome
intermediation fees. Still, the risks of the investment were ultimately
born by these dispersed investors.
Since
these small and dispersed investors found it difficult to organize
among themselves — and since gunboat diplomacy and military invasion had
been delegitimized as a crisis resolution mechanism in the wake of WWI,
and there was still no equivalent to the IMF to come to the rescue of
private creditors — the debtor countries were in a relatively powerful
position to default on their loans once they hit the hard times of
crisis in the 1930s. In a word, the small and dispersed private
bondholders were powerless: they simply could not resist default.
The Structural Power of Wall Street
This
contrasts markedly with the sovereign lending regime of the 1970s. By
1982, bank syndication had largely replaced bond finance as the main
form of lending to governments. This time around, Wall Street banks
syndicated loans to Latin American governments, bringing together
numerous banks to put up adequate amounts of capital, but concentrating
the debt firmly on the balance sheets of some of the biggest and largest
US-based banks. Suddenly, the bulk of Latin America’s debt was held by
some of Wall Street’s most powerful banks.
This,
combined with the existence of the IMF — which had been set up in the
wake of WWII and was now being reformed into a neoliberal handmaiden of
the Reagan administration — changed everything. A wave of defaults by
the Latin debtors now threatened the very stability of the global
financial system, while the syndicated nature of lending allowed the
banks to organize a closely-knitted “creditors’ cartel”. Colluding with
the US government and the IMF, the banks isolated the debtors through a
case-by-case approach to debt negotiation, pitching a united creditor
front against a series of helpless individual debtors.
As
a result, the new financial structure allowed the big Wall Street banks
to exert enormous power over their debtors, without even having to
resort to lobbying or other direct forms of exercising political
influence. By the 1980s, the power base of the big banks had become
structural in nature: if the debtors failed to pay up, the bankers could
credibly threaten that they would cut the debtors off from the global
financial system altogether simply by immediately withdrawing all
outstanding investments and refusing to extend any new credit.
This
ability to withhold and withdraw credit — which would have had dramatic
consequences for the ability of Latin American governments to import
food or oil, for instance, or to continue funding basic social
expenditures — gave the Wall Street banks a unique form of structural
power over debtor governments. Working together closely with the US Fed,
the Treasury Department and the IMF, large bailouts were organized that
imposed highly punitive conditions on the debtors, while always
insisting on full repayment for the banks.
The Argentine Exception of 2001
If
anything, Argentina in 2001 proved to be an exception to this evolving
rule. While the Latin American debt crisis of the 1980s and the
East-Asian financial crisis of the late 1990s had both revolved around
an increasing concentration of lending in an ever-shrinking oligopoly of
powerful Wall Street banks, lending to Argentina in the late 1990s had
once again taken the form of bond finance. Argentina’s creditors, in
other words, were mostly small and dispersed individual investors, like
ordinary middle-class households in Italy.
When
the Argentine crisis initially hit, the Wall Street banks that had
exposure to Argentina immediately tried to dump their bonds on secondary
markets — selling them on at lower face value to hedge funds and to
those same small investors in Europe. Unaware of the risks they were
taking on, for instance, many Italian pension funds simply poured the
life savings of millions of middle-class Italian families into the risky
Argentine bonds that the Wall Street banks were now trying to get rid
off. The results were catastrophic.
By
December 2001, it had become clear that Argentina’s debt load had
become both economically and politically unsustainable. Widespread
social unrest was undermining the legitimacy of the ruling elite, and
the introduction of the corralito
— which imposed draconian withdrawal limits on bank deposits — led to a
social explosion that threatened to destabilize the entire state
apparatus. Still, as Paul Blustein records in his account of the crisis, Wall Street bankers had to convince Argentine policymakers of the inevitability of default.
So
rather than the Argentine government imposing a dramatic default on
powerful Wall Street banks, as both the populist propaganda of the
Kirchner government and the uninformed interpretation of the
international media would have it, Argentina’s default was actually
actively pushed for by Wall Street bankers, who had long seen the
collapse coming and had already offloaded their exposure. While Wall
Street did suffer some losses, it was the ordinary, dispersed,
unsuspecting and therefore powerless bondholders who suffered the brunt
of the default.
Structural Power in the European Debt Crisis
In
the build-up to the European crisis, by contrast, the pendulum once
again swung back to debt concentration in the biggest and most powerful
banks. While Greece’s accumulated debt was mostly in the form of
sovereign bonds, these bonds were concentrated in some of Europe’s most
powerful banks: BNP Paribas, Société Générale and Crédit Agricole of
France, Deutsche Bank and Commerzbank of Germany, and ING of the
Netherlands. Meanwhile, the same core banks invested heavily in
Portuguese and Italian bonds and in Spanish and Irish real estate.
As
a result, when the European crisis first hit in early 2010, those
players who stood to lose the most were the powerful banks of the core.
These banks had become so systemically important to the global financial
system that a collapse of one of them would have had dramatic
repercussions for the system as a whole. Ironically, this vulnerability
gave the banks enormous structural power over the process of crisis
management: without even exerting any direct pressure, the banks could
virtually outlaw default as a realistic policy response.
In
other words, Latin America’s lessons for Europe are more troubling than
one would think. When sovereign lending becomes concentrated in the
hands of a few systemically important and structurally powerful banks,
the interests of debtor nations will tend to be undermined in dramatic
fashion — with all the concomitant repercussions for living standards
and democratic processes. Rather than expecting an Argentine-style
default anytime soon, perhaps what we really should be expecting is
another lost decade of austerity and deferred dreams.
Time for a Push?
And
yet it would be foolish to give up the struggle — especially when the
lives of millions of Europeans depend on it. It is here that the
Argentine lessons of 2001-’02 are most instructive and hopeful. In fact,
it is not the nature of Argentina’s crisis management but rather the
nature of its popular uprising that should be a source of inspiration to
those in the European periphery today. What the piqueteros
taught us in December 2001, is that the only way to force a capitalist
state to respond to its people in times of crisis is by systematically
destroying that state.
Of course, the
Argentine state eventually survived — thanks in large part to the
populist measures undertaken by the Kirchner government — but not before
a spontaneous popular uprising had destabilized it to the point where
default had become the only option left for its embattled elite. This,
then, appears to be Latin America’s lasting lesson for Europe: a
crisis-ridden and heavily indebted capitalist state will not simply jump
over the edge and surrender to the will of the people. To default on
its debts, it will need to be pushed — and we remain the only ones who
can do the pushing.
No comments:
Post a Comment